Pablo Hernández de Cos : The role of macroprudential policy in the stabilisation of macro-financial fluctuations

2023-10-09 IMI

Speech by Mr Pablo Hernández de Cos, Governor of the Bank of Spain, at the Conference on Financial Stability, organised by the Banco de Portugal, Lisbon, 2 October 2023.  


Ladies and gentlemen, bom día.


Thank you very much for your kind introduction, Mario, and thank you for inviting me to this conference. It is always a pleasure to come to Lisbon.


I would like to use this opportunity to consider the role of macroprudential policy in the stabilisation of macro-financial fluctuations and ways to enhance this role.


Macroprudential policy objectives


The  global financial  crisis taught  us  some  important  lessons from  a  financial  stability perspective. Firstly, that individual financial institutions needed greater and higher quality capital and liquidity buffers. Second, that an exclusively microprudential approach to capital requirements  cannot  take into account how the  actions of individual banks impact the financial system as a whole, interacting with those of other banks and of the rest of the players in the system, and influencing the probability of future crises.


As a consequence, and focusing on the banking sector, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision  (BCBS)   undertook   an  ambitious   overhaul   of  the   prudential   regulatory framework, known as Basel III, which is now very close to being fully transposed into the legislation of the main jurisdictions.


Together with a strengthening  of microprudential  requirements  to boost individual bank resilience, a significant aspect of this reform was the introduction of macroprudential policy, with the specific goal of mitigating the accumulation of systemic risk in the financial system, both over financial cycles (time dimension) and across financial market participants (cross- sectional dimension). The reasoning behind this goal is that the materialisation of systemic risk can impair the financial system and disrupt the  provision of financial servi ces, with serious negative effects for the real economy. 2


Importantly, macroprudential policy is designed not only to improve the resilience of the financial system against the materialisation of these two dimensions of systemic risk, but also to  lean  against  the  root  causes of  systemic  threats  and  vulnerabilities  and  their accumulation over time.


Indeed, even if macroprudential  policy does not fully eliminate systemic risk, empirical evidence suggests that it can significantly reduce it. Moreover, limiting the aggregate risk assumed during financial expansions reduces the severity of systemic risk materialisation. And  the accumulation of capital buffers to absorb losses during  bust periods allows a speedier recovery in the provision of financial services to the real economy .


Moreover, bearing in mind that, through a number of different channels, financial conditions can be a major driver of the business cycle, the conduct of an active macroprudential policy will also generally help to temper the growth of nominal and real activity in boom phases and also their decline during downturns, which should moreover become less frequent.



Hence, macroprudential policy can be conducive to a less volatile growth path and less hysteresis during crises.


In this regard, macroprudential policy can be seen as a complement to monetary and fiscal policies with regard to their macroeconomic stability objective.


The role of macroprudential policies in stabilising the economy might be particularly relevant in the European Monetary Union (EMU), where a common monetary policy is shared by countries whose economic and financial cycles are still heterogeneous and where, in the absence of a common permanent  fiscal capacity, national  fiscal policy is left  alone to counteract  the negative  consequences of idiosyncratic shocks or common shocks that generate different heterogeneous effects across member countries .


Looking  ahead,  this  potential  stabilisation  role  of  macroprudential   policy  could  be particularly relevant given the presence of high levels of structural public deficits and debt in many countries, which has significantly reduced the space available for fiscal policy to play its stabilisation role.


The outbreak of the COVID-19 pandemic, when fiscal, monetary and macroprudential policies acted jointly to support the real economy, illustrates this stabilization role. However, macroprudential policy was constrained by the fact that the accumulated macroprudential buffers existing at its onset were small or non-existent in many jurisdictions, given the pre- crisis context of very limited signs of any build-up of financial systemic risk.


A stronger role of macroprudential policy to effectively address adverse shocks that occur independently of the financial cycle – as the COVID crisis - will require, therefore, increasing the policy space generated by macroprudential buffers.


Capital buffers and buffer usability


In  the  case  of  the  banking  sector  –  that  part  of  the  financial   system  for  which macroprudential policy is most developed – capital buffer requirements and limits on lending standards are the main macroprudential tools.


Let me focus on capital buffers. In Europe, for example, the combined buffer requirements (CBR), which are placed on top of minimum  capital requirements,  comprise the  capital conservation buffer, the  systemic risk  buffer, buffers for global and  other systemically important institutions and the countercyclical capital buffer (CcyB). Importantly, some of these buffers are releasable by authorities, in particular the CcyB.


This distinction between releasable a non-releasable buffers is key. When banks experience losses, they can decide on their own to dip into the macroprudential buffers to absorb them. This would not involve a breach of minimum capital requirements, but banks would still have to face restrictions on their profit distributions via dividend and bonus pay -outs and share buybacks. Or macroprudential authorities may decide to release the CcyB, which would automatically increase banks’ available voluntary buffers. In this second case, dipping into the enlarged voluntary buffer would not involve profit distribution restrictions for banks.


The CCyB has the primary objective of ensuring that the banking sector as a whole has an additional capital buffer,  beyond microprudential requirements,  which could be used to absorb losses in a downturn  that  is preceded  by a period of excessive credit growth associated with the  build-up  of systemic risks. During  business cycle downturns  and financial crises, banks would be allowed to use this additional capital headroom instead of deleveraging. In this manner, the CCyB would help to sustain the supply of credit to the economy in bad times. The initial regulatory focus for the CCyB is, therefore, the credit cycle and bank resilience.


What makes the CCyB different from non-releasable macroprudential buffers is, therefore, that it can be reduced (released) by the authorities (if necessary, all the way down to zero) when risk materialises. For a given level of an institution’s CET1 ratio, the release of all or part of the CCyB requirement means that the management buffer of the bank automatically increases.


What do we know about the effectiveness of this framework?


In contrast to microprudential policy, the effectiveness of macroprudential policy cannot be analysed simply by assessing whether a certain increase in the level of capital allows a given bank to absorb a systemic shock of a given intensity. This is certainly relevant, but the goal of macroprudential  policy is also to induce  banks to absorb losses while continuing to provide credit to the real  economy in times of stress and therefore  to smooth financial cycles.


In this regard, the effectiveness of macroprudential buffers depends on their usability, which can be defined precisely as the willingness of banks to dip into the buffers in order to maintain the flow of credit to the real economy. If buffer usability is low, banks will have greater incentives to deleverage in response to adverse macro -financial shocks.


The usability of voluntary buffers should not be taken for granted . Market  pressure and profitability considerations could provide incentives to banks to conserve these resources, and deleverage instead. Uncertainty  about the cost and time  path for rebuilding these buffers could also disincentivise their use.


The academic literature generally shows that higher capital ratios allow banks to satisfy loan demand  more easily, in particular in periods of stress. However, there  is more  limited agreement on whether the relevant factor is the total level of capital or the voluntary buffer, that is to say the gap between the actual level of capital and the capital requirements. This issue is highly relevant to the design of the macroprudential framework.


If the only relevant factor for smoothing financial cycles is the absolute level of capital, then macroprudential policy should concentrate its efforts on the accumulation of non-releasable buffers, assuming that banks will make use of them if they incur losses.


In contrast, if the relevant factor is not only the absolute level of capital, but the distance from capital requirements, then the availability of releasable macroprudential buffers could play  a  key  role  in  mitigating  the  impact  of  systemic  shocks, as  their  release  would automatically increase voluntary buffers and thus contribute to a stable provision of credit during periods of materialisation of losses.


The empirical evidence gathered in the euro area and the United States during the pandemic shows the unwillingness of banks to dip into regulatory buffers and that the size of voluntary buffers was the main factor determining the propensity of banks to keep lending to non- financial corporations (NFCs). In particular, banks with low capital headroom lent less during the pandemic than those banks with large voluntary buffers.


This is precisely the main reason behind the benefits of releasing buffers such as the CCyB during systemic events. The empirical studies assessing the role of released buffers in Europe during the pandemic show that they helped support the provision of credit to companies and households.


In particular, recent evidence from the United Kingdom shows that banks that benefitted more from the release of the CCyB, because they had either a higher share of credit within their risk-weighted assets or lower capital headroom, granted mortgages for higher amounts with lower interest rates during COVID-19.


Research under way at the Banco de España seemingly corroborates these benefits, by identifying, in particular, that banks increased lending in jurisdictions where the CCyB was released in response to the pandemic, and that these positive effects were mainly significant for the most capital constrained banks, which are precisely those banks found to cut lending more in the absence of measures.


For the particular case of the Spanish banking system, there is also evidence that voluntary buffers, not absolute capital levels, were more relevant determinants of the willingness ofbanks to continue lending during the COVID-19 crisis. Specifically, for banks with smaller voluntary buffers, it is possible to identify a significant negative (differential) variation in the supply of loans to NFCs with which they had more recent, and hence weaker, banking relationships.

Furthermore, when loans with COVID-19 public guarantees (which introduced a significant positive credit supply shock) are excluded from the analysis, institutions with lower voluntary buffers  are  found  to have  granted  significantly  less overall credit  to  NFCs  during  the pandemic. This shows that the COVID-19 public guarantees compensated for the higher propensity of banks with lower voluntary buffers to reduce their loan supply. Hence, this finding adds up to the evidence that the interaction of fiscal policy and financial stability proved fundamental in the pandemic, in a context in which there were no releasable capital buffers, as was the case for Spain.


Increasing releasable macroprudential buffers


Two main conclusions can be drawn from the available evidence summarised above. First, banks seem to be unwilling to dip into their unreleased buffers when losses materialise, which means that buffers may not fulfil their role as shock absorbers. Second, releasable buffers (the CCyB, mainly) seem to be used by banks when released.  The main corollary of this evidence should be that there might be a need to increase releasable buffers that can be released during crises, in particular the CCyB.

In addition, as discussed in the first part of my address, there might be reasons to defend a more flexible and active use of the CCyB.

Under the current framework, the activation of the CCyB is linked only to signals of systemic credit imbalances. The experience during the outbreak of the COVID-19 pandemic, and, to some extent, also from the Russian invasion of Ukraine and the subsequent high level of geopolitical tensions, has shown, however, that a systemic crisis can and does arise for reasons exogenous to the economic and financial systems. As these exogenous shocks are unpredictable and may not be preceded by a financial boom that warrants the activation of the CCyB, under the original framework we cannot guarantee that the CCyB will be at a positive level when they arise.

Moreover, if we would like to use the CCyB as a complement to  the traditional macroeconomic stabilising policies, its activation would also be required even if signals of credit imbalances are neutral, for example in the presence of a positive output gap.

This flexible and more active use would also mitigate the inaction bias, which is another common concern in the area of macroprudential policies.


However, the practical implementation of higher releasable buffers poses several important questions.


In particular, when evaluating the introduction of more releasable macroprudential capital buffers, it is necessary to consider whether it can be neutral in terms of total capital levels, both at inception and at different points of the financial cycle. In fact, higher capital ratios ina steady state could have a dampening effect on credit provision and, therefore, on potential GDP, so it is crucial to evaluate whether these costs are offset by the benefits in terms of lower probabilities of financial crises and, should they arise, of them being shallower.


If the overall capital levels are to be preserved in periods of stress, total capital requirements must increase during booms or even normal and intermediate times. This approach would be capital neutral in periods of stress, but entail an overall capital increase in other periods, and hence through the cycle. Otherwise, the greater release and use of capital buffers during busts could leave banks, and indeed the whole financial system, more vulnerable to further losses in periods of stress. The alternative, increasing releasable buffers while maintaining current capital levels, would be capital neutral at inception, but it would plausibly entail lower capital through the cycle.

This debate has given rise to the concept of a positive neutral CCyB in normal times, first introduced by the Bank of England in 2016. This term refers to the introduction of a positive CCyB requirement level even in the absence of financial imbalances. Since the outbreak of the pandemic, the debate has naturally gained ground in many institutions. Indeed, the Basel Committee published last year a newsletter clarifying that the Basel framework leaves open the possibility of introducing a positive neutral CCyB. The ECB and the ESRB have also reiterated their support for this approach. Indeed, many European countries have gradually adopted this new CCyB calibration approach in recent years, including Croatia, Cyprus, Estonia, Ireland, Lithuania, the Netherlands, Norway and Sweden.

Let me illustrate how a positive neutral CCyB can be set throughout the financial cycle. To this end, I will take as a reference the analytical framework described by De Nederlandsche Bank, where four different phases associated  with the  degree  of systemic  risk  are distinguished. First, the recovery phase, which is the one that follows a crisis, is a period of recovery of deteriorated balance sheets, both in the financial system and among households and businesses. In this phase, the CCyB is maintained at zero. Second, in the normality phase, the balance sheet recovery is well under way and the CCyB is built up to reach the neutral level. Third, in the phase of increased risk, when excessive developments in lending or asset prices lead to higher systemic risk, the CCyB should be raised above the neutral level. Finally, in the materialisation phase, risk materialises and the CCyB is fully or partly released.

Obviously, not all these phases need to happen in the aforementioned stylised order. For example, the phase of increased risk could be curbed as a consequence of the increase in the CCyB above neutral levels or the use of other macroprudential tools. If that is the case, the CCyB could be progressively released to the neutral level. Or, after reaching the neutral level, the economy could enter a recession abruptly, before vulnerability signals accumulate, thus entailing losses for the banking system. Depending on the circumstances, a total or partial release of the buffer could be advisable to smooth the business cycle, thus helping monetary and fiscal policy to close the output gap.

A decision on introducing a positive neutral CCyB should weigh up the different pros and cons of such an approach.

Regarding the costs and benefits, the estimations of the elasticity of credit and GDP to changes in capital requirements during recessions and expansions could be useful. In the Spanish case,  for  example, the available evidence shows that an  increase  in  an expansionary period of 1 percentage point (pp) in the capital-to-risk-weighted assets ratio, consistent with a tightening of credit requirements, would not have negative effects on total credit to the corporate sector, while it would lead to a reduction of 0.5 pp in credit to households and of 0.2 pp in GDP. By contrast, the same amount of capital being released during a crisis would lead to an increase of up to 3.5 pp in credit to households and the corporate sector and of 1.6 pp in GDP.

This evidence supports the existence of an asymmetry between the costs of activating the CCyB in normal times, even in the absence of significant systemic imbalances, and the benefits of its release during downturns. The gradual activation of the buffer at an early stage makes capital planning easier for banks when conditions are good, reducing potential negative credit supply effects of the activation. It allows also to take into account uncertainty in the identification of risks, which can result in a delay and a more rapid activation later in the cycle.

But the analysis of the pros and cons is more complex. In this regard, a key problem for a macroprudential policymaker is to decide whether we are in “normal times” at a particular time. In this regard, authorities can employ a broad range of indicators, including the credit- to-GDP gap and other financial and macroeconomic metrics , such as the output gap.

Furthermore,  it is also necessary to assess the appropriate neutral  level of the CCyB in normal times. This may depend on:

-      The (cyclical and structural) characteristics of the domestic economy that can affect the estimated intensity of systemic crises.

-      The  desired level of macroeconomic  stabilisation capacity afforded to national macroprudential  policies in  light  of the  available buffers in other policy instruments.

-      The (cyclical and structural) characteristics of the banking system, such as  the  intensity  of competition and  sectoral  composition of assets and liabilities, which can affect the capacity to withstand potential shocks, under both baseline and adverse scenarios.

-      Other  factors,  such  as  the   degree  of  domestic  and   cross -border interconnectedness of the financial system and the overall economy, also

need  to  be  considered. These  factors have  a  significant  impact  on the vulnerability of the economy to internal and external shocks.

Authorities that have moved to a positive neutral  CCyB have used different approach to calibrate the positive neutral rate, including analyses of historical losses, stress test models, assessments of the impact of buffer releases during the pandemic and expert judgement.

All these considerations, which may vary among jurisdictions and therefore could condition the desirability of moving to a positive neutral CCyB, justify the position of the BCBS, which supports and sees the benefits of the authorities’ ability to set a positive cycle-neutral CCyB rate voluntarily.

In  particular, the  Committee noted that  circumstances indeed vary across jurisdictions, including the macroeconomic conditions and the range of macroprudential tools available, for example sectoral buffers, and their use to generate sufficient capital for banks to absorb unpredictable shocks. As a result, not all authorities consider a positive cycle-neutral CCyB rate to be appropriate in their jurisdictions.

In any case, it was considered important to stress that in the event authorities implement such  an approach, they  should continue  to comply with the  existing Basel standards, including the agreed calibration of the minimum requirements and other regulatory buffers.


Conclusions


Macroprudential policy emerged as a new policy domain only after the global financial crisis. Ever since, we have witnessed and suffered fresh systemic crises and turmoil stemming from exogenous shocks, such as the COVID-19  pandemic and the  Russian invasion of Ukraine, while macroprudential policy was designed to address events of systemic stress that  are fundamentally  endogenous to the financial  system. We have also found some indications of a positive relationship between lending and the capital headroom of banks (i.e.  the  surplus  of  a  bank’s  capital  above  all  minimum  regulatory  requirements  and regulatory buffers). As a result, there might be a case for increasing releasable buffers, in particular the  CCyB, and  for defending a more flexible use of this tool considering  its potential for helping other policies in macroeconomic stabilisation.

In this regard, an increasing number of jurisdictions have chosen to implement positive cycle-neutral CCyB rates. Under this approach, authorities aim for a positive CCyB rate when risks are judged to be neither subdued nor elevated.

Authorities that have introduced positive cycle-neutral CCyB rates have found it helpful for banks in their jurisdictions to have capital buffers in place that can be released in the event of sudden shocks, including those unrelated to the credit cycle, such as the impact of the COVID-19  pandemic.  This  approach can  help  address concerns  that  banks  in some jurisdictions may be reluctant to cross regulatory buffer thresholds in times of stress, but may be more willing to use their capital to support lending when  buffers are explicitly released by authorities.

Looking ahead, rigorous analytical research will be essential to improve our understanding of the recent experience with systemic events and refine macroprudential policy so that we can enhance  its effectiveness and thereby release monetary and fiscal policy space to confront these challenges. I am glad to see that this conference is gathering some prominent contributors to this important effort.